2053

SEPTEMBER SERIES III – Fragile by Design: The Political Economy of Financial Stability in the United States and Canada, 1790–2013

Reading Time: 8 minutes - PDF *Abstract This article conducts a comparative historical analysis of the U.S. and Canadian banking systems to investigate the stark… >> https://granaria.ac/z9tt
Reading Time: 8 minutes -

Abstract

This article conducts a comparative historical analysis of the U.S. and Canadian banking systems to investigate the stark divergence in their long-term financial stability. Despite sharing proximate geographies, integrated economies, and similar macroeconomic trajectories, the United States has experienced 17 systemic banking crises since its founding, while Canada has experienced none. Standard economic models attributing crises to the inherent fragility of maturity transformation in banking are insufficient to explain this profound empirical discrepancy. We posit that the primary determinant of this divergence is not economic fundamentals but the political and regulatory structures governing the banking sector in each nation. The U.S., through a political equilibrium dominated by agrarian populist interests and reinforced by a constitutional structure that divided sovereignty over banking (states’ rights), adopted and maintained a “unit banking” model. This model legally mandated fragmentation and prohibited geographic diversification, thereby inducing systemic fragility by concentrating risk and preventing coordinated crisis response mechanisms. Conversely, Canada’s constitutional framework, which centralized banking authority at the federal level, enabled the formation of a consolidated system of nationwide branch banking characterized by inherent portfolio diversification and the capacity for ex-post coordination. We present evidence from historical balance sheets that market participants in both nations were aware of the differential risk profiles. We conclude that the persistence of financial fragility in the U.S. represents a political choice, not an economic inevitability, illustrating how foundational institutional design shapes long-run financial stability outcomes.

  1. Introduction

The study of financial crises has long been a central theme in economics. Seminal works have identified universal triggers and propagation mechanisms, such as asset price bubbles, asymmetric information, and the inherent liquidity mismatch of bank balance sheets (Kindleberger & Aliber, 2005; Diamond & Dybvig, 1983). While these models provide a crucial theoretical foundation, they struggle to account for the profound cross-country and inter-temporal variations in financial stability. A particularly salient anomaly, and the focus of this paper, is the comparative history of the United States and Canada.

Over a span of more than two centuries, these adjacent, highly integrated economies have exhibited polar opposite experiences with respect to banking system stability. The empirical record is unambiguous: the U.S. financial system has been characterized by recurrent, systemic crises, including major panics in 1819, 1837, 1857, 1873, 1893, 1907, the Great Depression of the 1930s, and the Global Financial Crisis of 2008. Canada, in stark contrast, has navigated the same global economic shocks, including the Great Depression, without a single systemic banking failure (Bordo, Redish, & Rockoff, 1994). This paper argues that this divergence cannot be explained by differences in macroeconomic volatility or by the fundamental nature of banking operations, which are structurally similar in both nations. Rather, the explanation lies in the distinct political economies that shaped their respective banking regulations from their inception.

The central thesis, drawing on the framework of Calomiris and Haber (2014), is that the U.S. political system fostered a fragmented, non-diversified banking structure known as unit banking, which was inherently crisis-prone. In contrast, Canada’s political structure facilitated a consolidated, nationwide branch banking system that was inherently robust. This analysis repositions the narrative of U.S. banking instability from one of unavoidable economic cycles to one of deliberate, though perhaps economically suboptimal, political choice.

  1. Theoretical Framework: Beyond Inherent Fragility to Institutional Design

The conventional model of bank instability posits that the practice of funding illiquid, long-term assets with liquid, short-term, “first-come, first-served” liabilities creates an inherent vulnerability to depositor runs (Diamond & Dybvig, 1983). A negative shock to asset values can trigger a crisis of confidence, leading to a self-fulfilling panic that forces fire-sales of assets and results in insolvency. While this mechanism is plausible, its universal applicability is challenged by cases like Canada, where banks with identical maturity transformation structures have avoided crises for centuries.

This suggests the presence of mediating institutional factors that either amplify or mitigate this inherent fragility. We identify two such factors at the system level:

Portfolio Diversification (Ex-Ante Risk Management): The ability of a banking institution to diversify its loan portfolio across geographies, industries, and asset classes is a primary determinant of its resilience to localized or sector-specific shocks. A geographically restricted bank is a non-diversified portfolio by definition. A nationwide bank, conversely, can offset losses in one region (e.g., a collapse in cotton prices) with gains in another (e.g., a boom in manufacturing), significantly reducing the covariance of its asset returns (Winton, 1999).

Systemic Coordination (Ex-Post Crisis Management): The capacity for banks within a system to coordinate a response to a liquidity shock or the impending failure of a peer institution can prevent contagion and contain systemic risk. In a concentrated system, leading banks can form clearinghouses that act as quasi-lenders of last resort, organize “lifeboat” operations to rescue a troubled peer, or collectively manage public perception to avert panic (Gorton & Mullineaux, 1987). In a highly fragmented system, the collective action problem becomes insurmountable.

Our framework posits that regulatory structures, which are themselves the outcome of a political process, directly determine the degree to which a banking system can achieve diversification and coordination.

  1. Empirical Analysis: The U.S.-Canada Dichotomy

3.1. The Structural Variable: Unit Banking vs. Branch Banking
The determinative difference between the U.S. and Canadian systems was the legal framework governing bank geography. For most of its history, the U.S. enforced a policy of unit banking, restricting banks to a single physical location. This legal constraint directly prevented portfolio diversification. A bank in rural Illinois in the 1920s, for example, was entirely exposed to the price volatility of corn and soybeans. When agricultural prices collapsed, so did the bank.

In contrast, Canada’s Bank Act of 1871 codified and encouraged nationwide branch banking. The dominant Canadian banks (e.g., Bank of Montreal, Royal Bank of Canada) operated extensive branch networks across the country, creating portfolios that were naturally diversified against regional and sectoral shocks. During the Great Depression, while over 9,000 U.S. banks failed—mostly in agricultural regions—not a single Canadian bank failed. They were able to absorb losses from the hard-hit prairie provinces because of their offsetting business in more stable central Canada (Bordo, Redish, & Rockoff, 1995).

Furthermore, this structural difference had profound implications for ex-post crisis management. The U.S. system, comprising over 20,000 atomized unit banks by the 1920s, lacked the institutional capacity for coordination during a panic. In Canada, the banking system was a stable oligopoly of a dozen or fewer major institutions. This small number of players facilitated the creation of powerful industry bodies and informal agreements to ensure mutual support. For instance, when the Sovereign Bank of Canada faced collapse in 1908, a consortium of other banks, orchestrated by the Bank of Montreal, arranged an orderly liquidation to prevent a panic, ensuring all depositors were paid in full (Schull, 1958).

3.2. Market Perception of Risk: Balance Sheet Evidence
The differential risk environments were recognized by market participants. A comparative analysis of historical bank balance sheets reveals that U.S. banks systematically maintained higher levels of capital and liquidity buffers relative to their Canadian counterparts as a form of self-insurance. For the period 1870-1913, U.S. national banks held significantly higher cash-to-asset ratios and equity-to-asset ratios than Canadian chartered banks (Calomiris, 2000). This indicates that U.S. bankers were acutely aware of the heightened idiosyncratic and systemic risks imposed by the unit banking structure and attempted to compensate by operating with more conservative balance sheets. Despite these precautionary measures, the system remained crisis-prone, underscoring the dominance of structural fragility over individual bank risk management.

3.3. Macroeconomic Outcomes and the “More Credit, More Stability” Paradigm
A common assumption is that there is a trade-off between financial stability and the provision of credit. The U.S.-Canada comparison, however, challenges this notion. Data show that bank credit as a percentage of GDP tracked closely in both nations until the late 20th century, after which Canada’s provision of credit surpassed that of the U.S. (Haber, 2005). This finding is consistent with the 18th-century Scotland-England comparison, where the stable, freely-entered Scottish banking system provided more credit than England’s fragile, monopolistic system (White, 1984). The Canadian model demonstrates that stability, innovation, and credit depth are not mutually exclusive outcomes; a well-structured system can deliver all three.

  1. The Political Determinants of Institutional Choice

The persistence of the economically suboptimal unit banking structure in the U.S. can only be understood as a political equilibrium.

Constitutional Structure: The U.S. Constitution created a system of dual banking, with sovereignty divided between the federal government (for national banks) and the states (for state-chartered banks). This allowed individual states to enact restrictive branching laws to protect local banking monopolies and cater to local political demands (White, 2013).

The Agrarian Populist Coalition: This system was sustained by a powerful coalition of agrarian populist interests. This constituency, influential from the Jacksonian era through the early 20th century, harbored a deep-seated suspicion of centralized financial power (“Wall Street” and the “Money Trust”), fearing that large, national banks would neglect local credit needs and exercise monopoly power. The unit bank, while fragile, was viewed as a captive local lender, providing a form of credit insurance for local economies. This political preference was powerful enough to defeat numerous reform proposals. The National Monetary Commission of 1910, for example, commissioned multiple volumes praising the Canadian system but omitted branching reform from its final recommendations due to its political infeasibility (Johnson, 1910).

In Canada, the British North America Act of 1867 (now the Constitution Act, 1867) granted the federal government exclusive jurisdiction over banking and currency. This constitutional provision insulated the banking structure from the localized political pressures that fragmented the U.S. system. Consequently, Canada’s regulatory framework could be designed with a primary focus on systemic stability, leading to the establishment of a consolidated, nationwide system that served the dominant commercial interests of the new nation (Breckenridge, 1910).

  1. Conclusion

The divergent histories of the U.S. and Canadian banking systems provide a powerful case study in the political economy of financial regulation. The chronic instability of the American system was not an unavoidable feature of capitalism but a direct consequence of a regulatory structure—unit banking—that was deliberately chosen and sustained for political reasons. This structure systematically inhibited diversification and coordination, rendering the system fragile by design. Canada’s stability, conversely, was the product of a constitutional and political framework that permitted the development of a resilient, consolidated banking system.

This analysis concludes that understanding the risk of financial crises requires moving beyond purely economic models to incorporate the political bargains and foundational institutional frameworks that shape financial architecture. The persistence of crisis-prone systems can often be traced to durable political coalitions that benefit from, or ideologically prefer, the very structures that generate systemic risk. The American experience serves as a cautionary tale about the long-term economic costs of prioritizing localized political goals over principles of sound financial design.

References

Bordo, M. D., Redish, A., & Rockoff, H. (1994). The U.S. Banking System from a Northern Exposure: Stability versus Efficiency. Journal of Economic History, 54(2), 325–341.
Bordo, M. D., Redish, A., & Rockoff, H. (1995). A Comparison of the United States and Canadian Banking Systems in the Twentieth Century: Stability and Efficiency. In M. D. Bordo & R. Sylla (Eds.), Anglo-American Financial Systems: Institutions and Markets in the Twentieth Century. Irwin Professional Publishing.
Breckenridge, R. M. (1910). The History of Banking in Canada. National Monetary Commission, U.S. Government Printing Office.
Calomiris, C. W. (2000). U.S. Bank Deregulation in Historical Perspective. Cambridge University Press.
Diamond, D. W., & Dybvig, P. H. (1983). Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity. Journal of Political Economy, 91(3), 401–419.
Gorton, G., & Mullineaux, D. J. (1987). The Joint Production of Confidence: Endogenous Regulation and 19th Century Commercial-Bank Clearinghouses. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 19(4), 457–468.
Haber, S. H. (2005). The Political Economy of Financial Development: Evidence from the Political History of Branch Banking in the United States and Mexico. The Journal of Policy History, 17(2), 169–192.
Johnson, J. F. (1910). The Canadian Banking System. National Monetary Commission, U.S. Government Printing Office.
Kindleberger, C. P., & Aliber, R. Z. (2005). Manias, Panics, and Crashes: A History of Financial Crises (5th ed.). Palgrave Macmillan.
Schull, J. (1958). 100 Years of Banking in Canada: A History of the Toronto-Dominion Bank. Copp Clark Publishing.
White, E. N. (2013). The Politics and Economics of State-Level Bank Regulation in the United States during the Nineteenth Century. In C. D. Romer & D. H. Romer (Eds.), The Political Economy of the Great Depression. National Bureau of Economic Research.
White, L. H. (1984). Free Banking in Britain: Theory, Experience, and Debate, 1800-1845. Cambridge University Press.
Winton, A. (1999). Don’t Put All Your Eggs in One Basket? Diversification and Specialization in Lending. Working Paper, University of Minnesota.**

Redaktion Granaria

redaktion granaria

Sprachen machen Leute und die Mehrsprachigkeit der Stadt schafft eine besondere Gemeinschaft. Diese lebt, denkt und schreibt hier. Denn wer sich äußert, der gestaltet.